The Lay of the Land: Prospects for Improving Financial Competitiveness
DOI:
https://doi.org/10.55016/ojs/sppp.v17i1.79993Abstract
Alberta’s financial sector has not grown to match the province’s overall rise in economic importance to Canada. From 1997 to 2022, Alberta’s population rose from 2.5 to 4.5 million and Alberta’s share of GDP rose from 11 per cent in 1997 to 14.9 per cent in 2021. Alberta’s financial sector, 14.7 per cent of Canada’s in 1997 and 15.3 per cent in 2022, barely budged.
A dynamic and efficient financial sector sustains long-term economic growth by allocating savers’ money to the highest value-added capital investments. These are usually innovations — either product innovations (making more or more valuable products from given inputs) or process innovations (making given outputs from less or less costly inputs). Either way, innovation adds to overall wealth by letting firms create more from less, the definition of productivity growth. The
more accurately the financial system allocates savers’ wealth, the faster standards of living, government tax bases and GDP can rise.
Various national and subnational governments throughout the world have enacted policies aimed at boosting productivity growth by better directing capital to its highest value uses, especially to finance innovation. These policies can be divided into two classes.
The first class of policies are direct government interventions. These are often counterproductive, at best ineffective, and successful only under unique conditions which do not prevail in Alberta.
Government can directly subsidize corporate R&D, industrial policies and business research programs, but has proven bad at picking winners and at keeping politics out of such decisions. Postwar industrial policies financed reconstruction in Europe and Japan, but rebuilding is fundamentally different from sustained long-term productivity growth. Otherwise, government interventions of this sort have near-perfect failure rates.
Some governments seek to boost economic activity by becoming “tax havens” — that is, by attracting businesses’ head offices with low tax rates. In general, this requires only a small office, or even just a post office address, in the tax haven. Tax havens are usually microstates with tiny populations, so small tax revenues from each of many notional head offices fund their small governments well. However, the strategy works less well for larger economies, such as Alberta. The largest tax haven, Ireland, boosted its GDP substantially, but only because national income accounting includes in its GDP the global sales of firms notionally headquartered there. Ireland’s GDP rose; its standard of living did not. Moreover, international agreements to penalize tax havens heavily are coming into force, and Canada’s interprovincial equalization program would likely reallocate any excess tax capacity Alberta gained.
Other governments seek to boost economic activity by “regulatory arbitrage” — that is, adopting laws and regulations that help firms avoid the laws and regulations of other jurisdictions. The U.S. state of Delaware has tailored its financial regulations, tax laws and other laws and regulations to gain revenue from incorporation and other business fees. Delaware lets firms claim the state as the place of their legal incorporation, even though their functional head offices and facilities
are elsewhere. One reason firms like Delaware is that its laws can be used to stop corporate takeovers. This can be economically destructive because takeovers can rejuvenate badly governed firms, but the consequences of corporate misgovernance need not affect Delaware. Regulatory arbitrage can induce a “race to the bottom,” in which jurisdictions outbid each other for fees by offering ever laxer laws and regulations. This often ends badly, as when Forbes magazine labelled the BC stock exchange the “scam capital of North America.” Small stock issuers had liked the BCSE’s lax regulations, but investors did not and the failing exchange was folded first into the Alberta Stock Exchange and later into the TSE Venture exchange.
The second class of policies require more effort, patience and wisdom, but often work. These have government focus on its core competences to improve the “lay of the land” to attract productivity-enhancing economic activity. This happens where governments provide public goods and services that people and firms deem worth the taxes.
For example, Delaware has expert economists vet its laws and regulations and vets its judges for their knowledge of economics. Consequently, Delaware courts provide uniquely economically literate resolutions of business disputes. To the extent that this, rather than legal and regulatory laxity, attracts companies, no race to the bottom ensues. Alberta might do likewise.
The two major U.S. high-tech hubs, Silicon Valley and Cambridge, are in California and Massachusetts, respectively — both relatively high tax states. Both hubs centre on elite research universities that provide ongoing supplies of brilliant high-tech entrepreneurs as well as financially and technologically highly skilled employees. Health care, school quality, law and order and other public goods and services figure into people’s decisions about where they study, found businesses and build lives. A growing local population of highly skilled people attracts more businesses seeking skilled employees, and this attracts more skilled employees. An economic law of gravity can take over to make a high-tech hub self-sustaining despite episodes of poor government. Venture capital firms, investment banks and other financial institutions arose to fund emerging high-value-added innovative firms.
Alberta may wish to evaluate legal, regulatory, health care, education and other public policy reforms by how they would improve the lay of the land. Policies that attract and retain innovative firms and the skilled workers they need boost productivity growth, the primary determinant of living standards. Alberta may also wish to review laws, policies, regulations and public-sector bureaucracies periodically and eliminate those that do not enhance the lay of the land.
Government worth the taxes can attract economic activity, and savings, from all over the world to Alberta. Government not worth the taxes, even if the taxes are low, sends economic activity and savings elsewhere. Fortunately, the lay of the land is most affected by things that lie within the traditional core competences of government: law, regulation, education, health care and the efficient provision of public goods and services that firms and people value for tax rates they deem worth paying to be in Alberta.
Downloads
Published
Issue
Section
License
The following is the copyright statement of SPPP.
Copyright © <Author name> <year>. This is an open-access paper distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons license CC BY-NC 4.0, which allows non-commercial sharing and redistribution so long as the original author and publisher are credited.
Publication Copyright and Licensing
The following guidelines and information, provided in six sections, are intended for authors (the “Author”) who are invited to write a paper (the “Work”) for The School of Public Policy Publications (the “Publisher”). The rights and responsibilities conveyed in the SPP Author Agreement will only apply once your paper is accepted for publication. At that point in the publication process, you will be asked to download the form and return a signed copy via e-mail to spppublications@ucalgary.ca. Please review the below information to ensure agreement with SPPP policies.
Section 1: Author’s Grant of Rights
In consideration of the Publisher’s agreeing to publish the Work in The School of Public Policy Publications, the Author hereby grants to the Publisher the following:
1.1 The irrevocable, royalty-free right to publish, reproduce, publicly display, publicly perform and distribute the Work in perpetuity throughout the world in all means of expression by any method or media now known or hereafter developed, including electronic format;
1.2 The irrevocable, royalty-free right to use the Author’s name and likeness in association with the Work in published form and in advertising and promotional materials related to the Work; and
1.3 The irrevocable, royalty-free right to license others to do any or all of the above.
Section 2: Prior Publication & Publication by Others
2.1 The Author agrees not to publish the Work, or authorize any third party to publish the Work, either in print or electronically, prior to publication of the Work by the Publisher.
2.2 The Author agrees not to publish the Work in any publication outlet which is substantially similar to The School of Public Policy Publications for a period of six (6) months after publication of the Work in The School of Public Policy Publications. Substantially similar is defined as a non-subscription, open-access publication outlet with a similar mandate/vision and intended audience.
2.3 Should the Author publish or distribute the Work elsewhere at any time or in any alternate format, the Author agrees to contact The School of Public Policy Publications to inform them of the subsequent publication.
2.4 Should the Author publish or distribute the Work elsewhere at any time or in any alternate format, the Author agrees to make reasonable efforts to ensure that any such additional publication cites the publication in The School of Public Policy Publications by author, title, and publisher, through a tagline, author bibliography, or similar means. A sample acknowledgement would be:
“Reprinted with permission from the author. Originally published in the The School of Public Policy Publications, http://www.policyschool.ca/publications/.”
Section 3: Editing and Formatting
The Author authorizes the Publisher to edit the Work and to make such modifications as are technically necessary or desirable to exercise the rights in Section 1 in differing media and formats. The Publisher will make no material modification to the content of the Work without the Author’s consent.
Section 4: Author’s Ownership of Copyright and Reservation of Rights
4.1 Nothing in this agreement constitutes a transfer of the copyright by the Author, and the copyright in the Work is subject to the rights granted by this agreement.
4.2 The Author retains the following rights, including but not limited to, the right:
4.2.1 To reproduce and distribute the Work, and to authorize others to reproduce and distribute the Work, in any format;
4.2.2 To post a version of the Work in an institutional repository or the Author’s personal or departmental web page so long as The School of Public Policy Publications is cited as the source of first publication of the Work (see sample acknowledgement above).
4.2.3 To include the Work, in whole or in part, in another work, subject to Section 2 above and provided that The School of Public Policy Publications is cited as the source of first publication of the Work (see sample acknowledgement above).
4.3 The Editors and Editorial Board of The School of Public Policy Publications requires authors to publish the Work under a Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommercial 4.0 International licence (CC BY-NC 4.0). This license allows others to distribute, remix, tweak, and build upon the Work for noncommercial purposes, and ensures the Author is credited for the original creation. This onward licensing is subject to section 2.4 of this agreement, which further ensures that the original publisher is credited.
Section 5: Author’s Warranties and Undertakings
The Author warrants that:
5.1 The Author is the sole author of the Work, or if a joint author, the Author has identified within the Work the other authors, and holds the copyright, either solely or jointly, and has the power to convey the rights granted in this agreement.
5.2 The Work has not previously been published, in whole or in part, except as follows:
5.3 Any textual, graphic or multimedia material included in the Work that is the property or work of another is either explicitly identified by source and cited in the Work or is otherwise identified as follows:
5.4 To the best of the Author’s knowledge, the Work does not contain matter that is obscene, libelous, or defamatory; it does not violate another’s civil right, right of privacy, right of publicity, or other legal right; and it is otherwise not unlawful.
5.5 To the best of the Author’s knowledge, the Work does not infringe the copyright or other intellectual property or literary rights of another.
5.6 The Author will indemnify and hold Publisher harmless against loss, damages, expenses, awards, and judgments arising from breach of any such warranties.
Section 6: The Reuse of Third-Party Works
The Publisher requires that the Author determine, prior to publication, whether it is necessary to obtain permissions from any third party who holds rights with respect to any photographs, illustrations, drawings, text, or any other material (“third-party work”) to be published with or in connection with your Work. Copyright permission will not be necessary if the use is determined to be fair dealing, if the work is in the public domain, or if the rights-holder has granted a Creative Commons or other licence. If either the Author or Publisher determines for any reason that permission is required to include any thirdparty work, the Author will obtain written permission from the rightsholder.